Skip to main content

 


ELASTICITY OF DEMAND

INTRODUCTION

Elasticity is a measure of a variable's sensitivity to a change in another variable, most commonly this sensitivity is the change in quantity demanded relative to changes in other factors, such as price.

In business and economics, price elasticity refers to the degree to which individuals, consumers, or producers change their demand or the amount supplied in response to price or income changes. It is predominantly used to assess the change in consumer demand as a result of a change in a good or service's price.

When the value of elasticity is greater than 1.0, it suggests that the demand for the good or service is more than proportionally affected by the change in its price. A value that is less than 1.0 suggests that the demand is relatively insensitive to price, or inelastic.

Inelastic means that when the price goes up, consumers’ buying habits stay about the same, and when the price goes down, consumers’ buying habits also remain unchanged.

If elasticity = 0, then it is said to be 'perfectly' inelastic, meaning its demand will remain unchanged at any price. There are probably no real-world examples of perfectly inelastic goods. If there were, that means producers and suppliers would be able to charge whatever they felt like and consumers would still need to buy them. The only thing close to a perfectly inelastic good would be air and water, which no one controls. 

Elasticity is an economic concept used to measure the change in the aggregate quantity demanded of a good or service in relation to price movements of that good or service.

A product is considered to be elastic if the quantity demand of the product changes more than proportionally when its price increases or decreases. Conversely, a product is considered to be inelastic if the quantity demand of the product changes very little when its price fluctuates.

For example, insulin is a product that is highly inelastic. For people with diabetes who need insulin, the demand is so great that price increases have very little effect on the quantity demanded. Price decreases also do not affect the quantity demanded; most of those who need insulin aren't holding out for a lower price and are already making purchases.

On the other side of the equation are highly elastic products. Spa days, for example, are highly elastic in that they aren't a necessary good, and an increase in the price of trips to the spa will lead to a greater proportion decline in the demand for such services. Conversely, a decrease in the price will lead to a greater than proportional increase in demand for spa treatments.

The demand for a commodity is affected by different economic variables: 

1.      Price of the commodity

2.      Price of related commodities 

3.      Income level of consumers

Types of Demand Elasticity

The quantity demanded of a good or service depends on multiple factors, such as price, income, and preference. Whenever there is a change in these variables, it causes a change in the quantity demanded of the good or service.

On the basis of different factors affecting the quantity demanded for a product, elasticity of demand is categorized into mainly three categories: Price Elasticity of Demand (PED), Cross Elasticity of Demand (XED), and Income Elasticity of Demand (YED)

Price Elasticity of Demand (PED)

Any change in the price of a commodity, whether it’s a decrease or increase, affects the quantity demanded for a product. For example, when there is a rise in the prices of ceiling fans, the quantity demanded goes down.  

This measure of responsiveness of quantity demanded when there is a change in price is termed as the Price Elasticity of Demand (PED).

The mathematical formula given to calculate the Price Elasticity of Demand is: 

PED = % Change in Quantity Demanded % / Change in Price

The result obtained from this formula determines the intensity of the effect of price change on the quantity demanded for a commodity. 

Income Elasticity of Demand (YED)

The income levels of consumers play an important role in the quantity demanded for a product. This can be understood by looking at the difference in goods sold in the rural markets versus the goods sold in metro cities. 

The Income Elasticity of Demand, also represented by YED, refers to the sensitivity of quantity demanded for a certain good to a change in real income (the income earned by an individual after accounting for inflation) of the consumers who buy this good, keeping all other things constant. 

The formula given to calculate the Income Elasticity of Demand is given as:

YED = % Change in Quantity Demanded% / Change in Income 

The result obtained from this formula helps to determine whether a good is a necessity good or a luxury good. 

 

Cross Elasticity of Demand (XED)

In a market where there is an oligopoly, multiple players compete. Thus, the quantity demanded for a product does not only depend on itself but rather, there is an effect even when prices of other goods change. 

Cross Elasticity of Demand, also represented as XED, is an economic concept that measures the sensitiveness of quantity demanded of one good (X) when there is a change in the price of another good (Y), and that’s why it is also referred to as Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand. 

The formula given to calculate the Cross Elasticity of Demand is given as: 

XED = (% Change in Quantity Demanded for one good (X)%) / (Change in Price of another Good (Y))

The result obtained for a substitute good would always come out to be positive as whenever there is a rise in the price of a good, the demand for its substitute rises. Whereas, the result will be negative for a complementary good. 

These three types of Elasticity of Demand measure the sensitivity of quantity demanded to a change in the price of the good, income of consumers buying the good, and the price of another good. 

 

Degrees of Price Elasticity of Demand

The effect of change in economic variables is not always the same on the quantity demanded for a product. 

The demand for a product can be elastic, inelastic, or unitary, depending on the rate of change in the demand with respect to the change in the price of a product. 

On the basis of the amount of fluctuation shown in the quantity demanded of a good, it is termed as ‘elastic’, ‘inelastic’, and ‘unitary’.

·         An elastic demand is one that shows a larger fluctuation in the quantity demanded of a product, in response to even a little change in another economic variable. For example, if there is a hike of $0.5 in the price of a cup of coffee, there are very high chances of a steep decline in the quantity demanded.  

·         An inelastic demand is one that shows a very little fluctuation in the quantity demanded with respect to a change in another economic variable. An example of this can be petrol or diesel.  

·         Unitary elasticity is one in which the fluctuation in one variable and quantity demanded is equal.

We can further classify these elastic and inelastic types of demand into five categories.

1.      Perfectly Elastic Demand

When there is a sharp rise or fall due to a change in the price of the commodity, it is said to be perfectly elastic demand. 

In perfectly elastic demand, even a small rise in price can result in a fall in demand of the good to zero, whereas a small decline in the price can increase the demand to infinity.  

However, perfectly elastic demand is a total theoretical concept and doesn’t find a real application, unless the market is perfectly competitive and the product is homogenous.  

The degree of elasticity of demand helps to define the slope and shape of the demand curve. Therefore, we can determine the elasticity of demand by looking at the slope of the demand curve. 

A Flatter curve will represent a higher elastic demand. Thus, the slope of the demand curve for a perfectly elastic demand is horizontal.

Fig 1: Perfectly elastic demand

2.      Perfectly Inelastic Demand

A perfectly inelastic demand is the one in which there is no change measured against a price change. 

Like perfectly elastic demand, the concept of perfectly inelastic is also a theoretical concept and doesn’t find a practical application. However, the demand for necessity goods can be the closest example of perfectly inelastic demand. 

The numerical value obtained from the PED formula comes out as zero for a perfectly inelastic demand. 

The demand curve for a perfectly inelastic demand is a vertical line i.e. the slope of the curve is zero. 

Fig 2: Perfectly inelastic demand

3.      Relatively Elastic Demand

Relatively elastic demand refers to the demand when the proportionate change in the demand is greater than the proportionate change in the price of the good. The numerical value of relatively elastic demand ranges between one to infinity. 

In relatively elastic demand, if the price of a good increases by 25% then the demand for the product will necessarily fall by more than 25%.

Unlike the aforementioned types of demand, relatively elastic demand has a practical application as many goods respond in the same manner when there is a price change. 

The demand curve of relatively elastic demand is gradually sloping.

Fig 3: Relatively elastic demand

4.      Relatively Inelastic Demand

In a relatively inelastic demand, the proportionate change in the quantity demanded for a product is always less than the proportionate change in the price. 

For example, if the price of a good goes down by 10%, the proportionate change in its demand will not go beyond 9.9..%, if it reaches 10% then it would be called unitary elastic demand (as shown in fig.5). 

The numerical value of relatively inelastic demand always comes out as less than 1 and the demand curve is rapidly sloping for such type of demand. 

Fig 4: Relatively inelastic demand

5.      Unitary Elastic Demand

When the proportionate change in the quantity demanded for a product is equal to the proportionate change in the price of the commodity, it is said to be unitary elastic demand. 

The numerical value for unitary elastic demand is equal to 1. The demand curve for unitary elastic demand is represented as a rectangular hyperbola. 

 

Fig 5: Unitary elastic demand

FACTORS THAT DETERMINE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND

There are three main factors that influence a good’s price elasticity of demand.

A.    Availability of Substitutes

In general, the more good substitutes there are, the more elastic the demand will be. For example, if the price of a cup of coffee went up by $0.25, consumers might replace their morning caffeine fix with a cup of strong tea. This means that coffee is an elastic good because a small increase in price will cause a large decrease in demand as consumers start buying more tea instead of coffee.

However, if the price of caffeine itself were to go up, we would probably see little change in the consumption of coffee or tea because there may be few good substitutes for caffeine. Most people, in this case, might not willingly give up their morning cup of caffeine no matter what the price. We would say, therefore, that caffeine is an inelastic product. While a specific product within an industry can be elastic due to the availability of substitutes, an entire industry itself tends to be inelastic. Usually, unique goods such as diamonds are inelastic because they have few if any substitutes.

B.     Necessity

As we saw above, if something is needed for survival or comfort, people will continue to pay higher prices for it. For example, people need to get to work or drive for a number of reasons. Therefore, even if the price of gas doubles or even triples, people will still need to fill up their tanks.

C.    The Proportion of Income Spent on the Good

The price elasticity of demand tends to be low when spending on a good is a small proportion of their available income. Therefore, a change in the price of a good exerts a very little impact on the consumer’s propensity to consume the good. Whereas, when a good represents a large chunk of the consumer’s income, the consumer is said to possess a more elastic demand.

D.    Time

The third influential factor is time. For instance, if the price of cigarettes goes up to $2 per pack, someone with a nicotine addiction with very few available substitutes will most likely continue buying their daily cigarettes. This means that tobacco is inelastic because the change in price will not have a significant influence on the quantity demanded. However, if that person who smokes cigarettes finds that they cannot afford to spend the extra $2 per day and begins to kick the habit over a period of time, the price of cigarettes for that consumer becomes elastic in the long run.

The Importance of Price Elasticity in Business

Understanding whether or not the goods or services of a business are elastic is integral to the success of the company. Companies with high elasticity ultimately compete with other businesses on price and are required to have a high volume of sales transactions to remain solvent. Firms that are inelastic, on the other hand, have goods and services that are must-haves and enjoy the luxury of setting higher prices.

Beyond prices, the elasticity of a good or service directly affects the customer retention rates of a company. Businesses often strive to sell goods or services that have inelastic demand; doing so means that customers will remain loyal and continue to purchase the good or service even in the face of a price increase.

Examples of Elasticity

There are a number of real-world examples of elasticity we interact with on a daily basis. One interesting modern-day example of the price elasticity of demand many people take part in even if they don't realize it is the case of Uber's surge pricing. As you might know, Uber uses a "surge pricing" algorithm during times when there is an above-average amount of users requesting rides in the same geographic area. The company applies a price multiplier which allows Uber to equilibrate supply and demand in real-time.

The COVID-19 pandemic has also shone a spotlight on the price elasticity of demand through its impact on a number of industries. For example, a number of outbreaks of the coronavirus in meat processing facilities across the US, in addition to the slowdown in international trade, led to a domestic meat shortage, causing import prices to rise 16% in May 2020, the largest increase on record since 1993.

Another extraordinary example of COVID-19's impact on elasticity arose in the oil industry. Although oil is generally very inelastic, meaning demand has a little impact on the price per barrel, because of a historic drop in global demand for oil during March and April, along with increased supply and a shortage of storage space, on April 20, 2020, crude petroleum actually traded at a negative price in the intraday futures market.

In response to this dramatic drop in demand, OPEC+ members elected to cut production by 9.7 million barrels per day through the end of June, the largest production cut ever.

CONCLUSION

Elasticity is an economic measure of how sensitive one economic factor is to changes in another. For example, changes in supply or demand to the change in price, or changes in demand to changes in income.

If demand for a good or service is relatively static even when the price changes, demand is said to be inelastic, and its coefficient of elasticity is less than 1.0.

Examples of elastic goods include clothing or electronics, while inelastic goods are items like food and prescription drugs.

Cross elasticity measures the change in demand for one good given price changes in a different, related good.

We can conclude the by stating the fact that the demand for a commodity is affected by several factors and the three main types of elasticity of demand explains the effect of those factors. 

To explain the extent of the effect of the economic variables on the quantity demanded, we have 5 other types of elasticity of demand which are perfectly elastic, perfectly inelastic, relatively elastic, relatively inelastic, and unitary elastic.


 

REFERENCE

Ayers; Collinge (2003). Microeconomics. Pearson. ISBN 978-0-536-53313-5.

 

Brownell, Kelly D.; Farley, Thomas; Willett, Walter C.; Popkin, Barry M.; Chaloupka, Frank J.; Thompson, Joseph W.; Ludwig, David S. (15 October 2009). "The Public Health and Economic Benefits of Taxing Sugar-Sweetened Beverages". New England Journal of Medicine. 361 (16): 1599–1605. doi:10.1056/NEJMhpr0905723PMC 3140416PMID 19759377.

 

Frank, Robert (2008). Microeconomics and Behavior (7th ed.). McGraw-Hill. ISBN 978-0-07-126349-8.

 

Gillespie, Andrew (1 March 2007). Foundations of Economics. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-929637-8. Retrieved 28 February 2010.

 

Goodwin; Nelson; Ackerman; Weisskopf (2009). Microeconomics in Context (2nd ed.). Sharpe. ISBN 978-0-618-34599-1.

 

Gwartney, James D.; Stroup, Richard L.; Sobel, Russell S.; David MacPherson (14 January 2008). Economics: Private and Public Choice. Cengage Learning. ISBN 978-0-324-58018-1. Retrieved 28 February 2010.

 

Krugman; Wells (2009). Microeconomics (2nd ed.). Worth. ISBN 978-0-7167-7159-3.

 

Landers (February 2008). Estimates of the Price Elasticity of Demand for Casino Gaming and the Potential Effects of Casino Tax Hikes.

 

Marshall, Alfred (1920). Principles of Economics. Library of Economics and Liberty. ISBN 978-0-256-01547-8. Retrieved 5 March 2010.

 

Mas-Colell, Andreu; Winston, Michael D.; Green, Jerry R. (1995). Microeconomic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-1-4288-7151-9.

 

https://corporatefinanceinstitute.com/resources/knowledge/economics/elasticity/

 

https://www.analyticssteps.com/blogs/elasticity-demand-and-its-types

 

https://www.investopedia.com/terms/p/priceelasticity.asp

 

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

THE EVOLUTION OF MARKETING

THE EVOLUTION OF MARKETING From the Stone Age to the post-modern digital era, our civilization has undergone a fascinating evolution in human history. The world of marketing is no different. In a free-market economy, marketing is so ubiquitous that we do not stop to think about how it started and grew to what it is today. How did people discover products in the early 1900s? It is hard to imagine, for this social media generation, how old folks traditionally did their commercial activities without smartphones. Marketing, in and of itself, has seen dramatic transformation for centuries. It started as a distinct discipline that went through different periods of refinement. With economic forces at the helm, businesses were faced with the reality of competing for customers’ attention while ensuring that they lock in their return on investment (ROI).  1.1       Eras that Shaped the Evolution of Marketing         i. ...

INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS

FUNCTIONS AND OBJECTIVES OF ORGANS OF UNITED NATION The United Nations (UN) is an international organization founded in 1945 in the aftermath of World War II, with the primary aim of preventing future conflicts and fostering international cooperation. Established by the Charter of the United Nations, the UN emerged as a successor to the League of Nations, which had failed to prevent the outbreak of the Second World War. The creation of the UN was driven by the desire to establish a more robust system of collective security and to promote global peace, security, and cooperation among nations (Bourantonis, 2005). The UN’s founding members, including the United States, the Soviet Union, the United Kingdom, China, and France, recognized the need for a new global institution to address international conflicts and challenges in a more effective manner. The UN's structure includes six main organs: the General Assembly, the Security Council, the International Court of Justice, the Secr...

THE CONCEPT OF A MARKET

  THE CONCEPT OF A MARKET The term market has more than one meaning: (a) A market is a place where people gather to transact business mainly to sell and buy commodities and other physical goods. (b) It can be used in respect of the network of institutions like wholesalers and brokers dealing in a product. (c) It can also be used to refer to the nature of demand for the product, as when we speak of the market for soap. (d) A market can be referred to as people with needs and wants, with enough disposable income to spend on goods and services provided to satisfy their special needs and wants and the willingness to expend their income on these goods and services. (e) Stanton (1981:65) defines a market as people with needs to satisfy, money to spend and willingness to spend it. 4.1        Market Segmentation Market segments refer to the sub-classes of the market reflecting sub-classes of wants and the process of conceptually distinguishin...